Untie the farmer
Written
by Ashutosh Varshney
The debate on the land
acquisition bill and the tragic suicide of a farmer in Delhi compel us to
reflect on a theme of enduring significance: the role of agriculture and
farmers in development. What has the historical experience all over the world been? How is India’s agrarian narrative
different — or identical? What can India learn from international experience?
Many
years ago, I wrote a book, Democracy, Development and the Countryside:
Urban-Rural Struggles in India. A great deal has changed since then. India has experienced its highest economic
growth rate since Independence and an urban
acceleration has set in. During 2001-11, for the first time since 1947, the
absolute increase in the urban population was greater than the absolute
increase in the rural population. Still, two-thirds of the nation continues to
live in the countryside. It is impossible to conceptualise the nation’s welfare
without rural wellbeing. How should rural welfare be imagined at this stage of
Indian development? What policies would be critical?
We should first note that agriculture declines as economic development takes
place. Allover Europe and North America, agriculture produces less
than 5 per cent of the nation’s GDP. Asia has not escaped this law of
development either. In 1990, agriculture accounted for 27 per cent of GDP in
China, 19 per cent in Indonesia and 15 per cent in Malaysia. By 2009-10, these
shares were down to 11 per cent in China, 13 per cent in Indonesia, 7 per cent
in Malaysia. In India, 31 per
cent of the nation’s GDP came from agriculture in 1990, declining to 14 per
cent by 2011-12.
Whereas
annual growth rates of 7-8 per cent in industry are
common, agriculture rarely grows at more than 4-5 per cent annually in the
medium to long run in developing countries. Over time, this means a steadily
declining share of agriculture in GDP. The locus of economic activity shifts
towards cities, industries and services. This, of course, does not mean that
agriculture can be neglected. Agriculture remains the producer of food, not
industry. Moreover, to populate the workforce in industry and services, labour
also comes primarily from the countryside. As Nobel laureate W. Arthur Lewis
argued, stagnant agriculture can neither produce enough food nor release enough
workers, whereas dynamic agriculture can do both. That is why a nation can’t
normally durably prosper if agriculture does not do well. Large food imports
are not a reliable option.
However,
since agriculture cannot generate enough opportunities for rural citizens, it
is better to link the countryside to industry and urban services. Cities do
have their share of problems: indeed, governance challenges in Indian cities
are formidable. But despite such problems, Bangalore and Mysore will grow
faster than Karnataka villages, Delhi and Meerut more rapidly than the Uttar
Pradesh countryside.
No
society has been able to help farmers by keeping them tethered to land. To
leave farmers on land and not give them skills for urban and industrial lives
is equal to trapping them in misery. Nor do younger rural folk wish to remain
in farming.
This
leads to two questions. How is politics connected to rural welfare? And how do
we make agriculture dynamic in such a way that farmers produce enough
as well as get more productively linked to the urban economy?
The
first question is easier to answer. India’s democracy has a rural thrust. More
voters still live in villages and, of late, villagers have also tended to vote
more than the urban folk. As a result, even though India’s urbanisation has
gathered speed, its governments are still by and large made or unmade in the
countryside. Cities may dominate the economic landscape, but villages are the
primary locus of political power. Political parties hurt themselves if they
neglect villages.
The
second question is more complicated. Rahul Gandhi recently argued in Parliament
that the previous government had raised the minimum support prices (MSP) for farmers at a significantly
higher rate than the current government, and that
is why agriculture did better under the UPA government but is currently
suffering. As is well known, the MSP is the guaranteed price at which the government buys
foodgrains and some other commodities from farmers.
Gandhi’s
argument was right for an earlier era, but is flawed for
the present times. Price incentives
are certainly a way to help farmers, but agricultural policy always needs a
balance between price and non-price measures. The more a
government provides price incentives to farmers, the less it has
for investments in upgrading the technological base of agriculture (irrigation,
agricultural research, electricity), for infrastructure connecting villages to
cities (roads, transport) and for rural health and education (which would
prepare rural citizens for opportunities in industry and services).
The
UPA’s agricultural policy was excessively price-led, both for outputs (crops)
and inputs (water, electricity, fertiliser). Wheat and rice were bought from
farmers in large quantities at high prices,
even though the country did not have enough warehouse capacity for storage,
leading to a considerable proportion of the procured wheat and rice rotting.
Public investment in agriculture rose inadequately. During 2012-13, more than
85 per cent of investment in agriculture was private. It is well known that
most of what lifts the technological base of agriculture and connects it
productively to urban opportunities requires public investment — in irrigation,
research, seeds, power, transport, schools, skills, etc.
Price incentives were absolutely necessary
to raise farm production at the time of the Green Revolution in the 1960s, when
India’s food production dropped abysmally. Indiadoes
not have a national crisis in food production today, as the high public stocks
show. But it has agrarian distress, for agricultural productivity is low and
skills for the exploitation of non-agrarian opportunities have not been
created. That can only come through a better balancing of price and non-price interventions.
Unless
agricultural strategy today is married to a 21st century vision of expansion of
opportunities, which requires linking, in a more integrated way, the village to
the city and agriculture to industry and services, we will only enhance the
misfortune and misery of India’s rural citizens.
The writer is Sol Goldman Professor of International Studies and
the Social Sciences at Brown University, where he also directs the India Initiative
at the Watson Institute. He is a contributing editor for ‘The Indian
Express’.